Governance practices in distributed-ledger systems have grown increasingly diverse and diffuse, while retaining a commitment to cryptoeconomics—the use of economic incentives to guide user behavior, in tandem with cryptographic technology. In the space of a few years, cryptoeconomics has introduced advances in techniques for self-governance. But reliance on cryptoeconomics also introduces limitations on governance possibilities. Drawing on earlier critiques of how economic logics can erode democracy, this paper identifies specific limitations that cryptoeconomic governance faces. It contends that, to overcome these limitations, designers should envelop cryptoeconomics within forms of politics capable of seeing beyond economic metrics for human flourishing and the common good.
This paper has benefited from generous feedback from readers including Eric Alston, Eva Beylin, Vitalik Buterin, Paul D’Aoust, Joel Dietz, Koray Caliskan, Alexander Lange, Mario Laul, Eugene Leventhal, Harry McLaverty, Auryn Macmillan, Kelsie Nabben, Brandon Ramirez, Lane Rettig, Julia Rosenberg, Sacha Saint-Leger, Jeremy Sklaroff, Lana Swartz, Michael Zargham, and Ethan Zuckerman. I am particularly grateful for the ongoing support of Primavera De Filippi, Morshed Mannan, and Wessel Reijers.
“The root problem with conventional currency is all the trust that’s required to make it work,” wrote pseudonymous Bitcoin inventor Satoshi Nakamoto in an early forum post announcing the invention—meaning, by “trust,” faith in banks, governments, and other sorts of “third party middleman” (Nakamoto 2009). In their place, Nakamoto offered a system of cryptography and economic incentives that would make digital money “secure” and “effortless.” After a little more than a decade, Nakamoto’s creation has swelled the lexicon of human self-governance to elevate once obscure or nonexistent terms such as proof of work, proof of stake, off-chain, on-chain, self-sovereign identity, holographic consensus, smart contracts, bonding curves, optimistic consensus, quadratic voting, governance tokens, and more. Billions of dollars’ worth of digital assets now rests on such jargon and the innovations it represents. For an observer of institutional designs, a Cambrian explosion appears to be underway among the organisms emanating from Nakamoto’s singular mutation.
And what became of trust? De Filippi et al. (2020) conclude that while the distributed-ledger technology underlying Bitcoin and its progeny has not fully escaped trust, it has produced a new kind of “confidence machine.” A convergence of technical and social features serves to produce confidence among users, apparently without need for trusted human intermediaries or the risks they bring. The partial shift from trust to confidence transfers governance burdens from people to technical systems, inviting a renaissance in designs for systems of governance.
For all the achievements of the renaissance underway, I propose to interrogate the inverse of its possibilities: What limitations does the confidence machine introduce? What governance options fall away when institutions seek to diminish the space of trust? What does the machine fail to measure or distort through measurement? These questions are especially urgent to the extent that distributed ledger technology represents a kind of prefigurative politics (Leach 2013), as many practitioners seek to replace the institutional infrastructure of political and economic life (Faustino 2019, Dicker 2021). Short of taking such “blockchain dreams” (Swartz 2017) as straightforwardly predictive, their ability to amass trillions of dollars in value suggests the dreams are beginning to remake waking life.
I refer to the dominant design logic that undergirds Bitcoin, derivative blockchains, and other distributed-ledger technologies with a colloquialism among practitioners, cryptoeconomics (Brekke and Alsindi 2021). The industry publication CoinDesk defines this “crucial concept” as “an area of applied cryptography that takes economic incentives and economic theory into account”—neither abstract cryptography nor economics but a practical fusion of the two (Stark 2017). The term is widely associated with Ethereum founder Vitalik Buterin (Voshmgir and Zargham 2020), according to whom “cryptoeconomics is fundamentally about the use of economic incentives together with cryptography to design and secure different kinds of systems and applications” (Buterin 2018). For example, Bitcoin’s cryptographic math protects the scarcity of units on its ledger; the perceived value of those units, in turn, motivates users to expend computing energy to perform expensive cryptographic math problems to win rewards. The math secures the economy, which in turn motivates people to use the math (Maurer et al. 2013, Babbitt and Dietz 2014).
For Buterin (2018), this has everything to do with trust: the goal is “to reduce social trust assumptions by creating systems where we introduce explicit economic incentives for good behavior and economic penalties for ba[d] behavior.” Traditional preconditions of trust such as personal familiarity (Luhmann 2000) and credentialed expertise (Giddens 1991) fall into obsolescence under the cryptoeconomic gale. In ways hard to fathom a few years ago, digital artifacts such as incomprehensible ledger addresses and scarce representations of non-scarce digital artworks have become regarded as valuable. Cryptoeconomics is producing the demise of bureaucracy, in one form, and its apotheosis in another (Laul 2021). Culture and ideology play roles in the successes of this technology, but cryptoeconomics above all summons it into being as the glue that makes the technology work and its users’ favorite topic of conversation.
The economics in cryptoeconomics brings with it a particular set of anxieties. Diverse voices have long warned against the expansion of economic logics, crowding out space for vigorous politics in public life. From the Zapatista insurgents of southern Mexico (Hayden 2002) to political theorists like William Davies (2014) and Wendy Brown (2015), the “neoliberal” aspiration for economics to guide all aspects of society represents a threat to democratic governance and human personhood itself. According to Brown:
neoliberalism transmogrifies every human domain and endeavor, along with humans themselves, according to a specific image of the economic. All conduct is economic conduct; all spheres of existence are framed and measured by economic terms and metrics, even when those spheres are not directly monetized. In neoliberal reason and in domains governed by it, we are only and everywhere homo oeconomicus (p. 10)
For Brown and other critics of neoliberalism, the ascent of the economic means the decline of the political—the space for collective determinations of the common good and the means of getting there. Brown continues:
as an economic framing and economic ends replace political ones, a range of concerns become subsumed to the project of capital enhancement, recede altogether, or are radically transformed as they are “economized.” These include justice (and its subelements, such as liberty, equality, fairness), individual and popular sovereignty, and the rule of law. They also include the knowledge and the cultural orientation relevant to even the most modest practices of democratic citizenship. (p. 22)
The things not visible to the market, that is, become unthinkable and impossible. If the market cannot see a changing climate, there is no motivation to act on it. If the market does not recoil at the plight of homelessness, neither can we, if we learn to be what the market sees in us.
Worries about the corrosive possibilities of economics on politics preceded the terminology of neoliberalism. Hannah Arendt (1998) observed how ancient Greek democratic thought regarded economics as a private matter, segregated from the political sphere. Athens’s sexist, slaver economy enabled citizens to enter politics as relative equals, whose “prepolitical” basic needs were already met, whose democracy could stand aloof from self-interest and corruption. To be a free and trustworthy citizen meant being free from susceptibility to economics, someone trustworthy when contemplating public life.
Arendt’s formulation of a politics wholly distinct from economy provides a useful foil for our purposes here. Let my references to politics refer to some approximation of Arendt’s: public speech concerned with the common good (ch. 2). Political institutions are domains for homo sapiens before homo economicus. They capture some sense of the general will; they protect certain essential rights of minorities and dissidents, although doing so may seem inconvenient or unprofitable. Even if politics cannot—and arguably should not—fully depart from economic life, what distinguishes politics is its capacity to notice and address less-economic considerations (Satz 2010, Bowles 2016). While a country’s taxation policy utilizes economic nudges, for instance, lawmakers must generally rationalize it according to conceptions of the common good, rather than optimizing for financial metrics. Politics is hardly immune to self-interest (Alston 2020), but incentives such as the need for politicians to run for reelection can introduce imperatives that economics alone would not.
Are concerns about corrosion by economics, such as those of Arendt and Brown, pertinent to cryptoeconomics? David Golumbia (2016) has argued forcefully that it is, recognizing the affinities that many blockchain designers have with far-right politics and Austrian School economists such as Friedrich Hayek, a godfather of neoliberalism. Golumbia regards this alignment as a fatal flaw. I contend there is need for more admiration for what cryptoeconomics has accomplished—including its ambivalence and its opening of possibilities. Jillian Crandall (2019), for instance, observes neoliberalism par excellence among crypto enthusiasts colonizing Puerto Rico, but she also identifies the technology’s potential for decolonial resistance. While Hayek retained at least a minimal role for the state in organizing markets, the designers of these systems hope they can go even further, supplanting governments with cryptography and incentives. Here, I find myself siding with the rejoinder to Hayek of Karl Polanyi (2014), who regarded markets as downstream from politics.
Worlds made of incentives elevate certain parts of us and suppress others, make some possibilities seem plausible and others not. Can we imagine a vital political act like solidarity, with the fellow-feeling and sacrifice it implies, taking form in cryptoeconomics? As with a gift (Mauss 2006), the presence of game-theoretic calculation might seem to undermine the power of prosocial acts. Flurries of tweets among strangers to “HODL!”—crypto-jargon for a call to “hold” tokens, in hopes of summoning the next bull market—are far from a sit-down strike in a car factory. The socially minded projects that some scholars have called “solidarity cryptocurrencies” are more the exception than the rule (Diniz et al. 2021); the closest cognate in the idiom of cryptoeconomics is “coordination.”
Meanwhile, a growing body of analysis interprets cryptoeconomics and its associated technologies as engines of commoning, in the spirit of Elinor Ostrom (Reijers et al. 2016, Rozas et al. 2018, 2021, Cila et al. 2020, Fritsch et al. 2021). There is much to commend this approach, as participant-governed blockchains do seem to resemble common-pool resources. Yet there are respects in which cryptoeconomics also resembles an opposite of the commons: the enclosure, in which what was once held in common becomes subdivided into ownable, tradable assets (Federici 2004). Under cryptoeconomics, things previously difficult or impossible to buy or sell, from cryptographic computing power to real estate in digital games, have become the basis of markets. Cryptoeconomic markets depend on some sort of artificial scarcity, such as Nakamoto’s limit on supply at 21 million bitcoins. More invasive forms of enclosure and scarcity could follow. In the past, major advances in commodification produced markets for enslaving human beings and conquering the once-common lands of indigenous peoples. Such comparisons might seem alarmist if cryptoeconomic enthusiasts were not setting their world-transforming sights so high.
I offer an analysis informed by unstructured interviews with participants in thirteen governance-related cryptoeconomic projects, selected through a snowball sampling process;[1] quotations from them are used with subsequent permission. I also took part in participant observation with several “decentralized autonomous organizations” (DAOs)[2] during the rise and fall of the 2020–2021 bull market, which saw historic highs in the value of leading cryptocurrencies. Drawing on these encounters, in what follows, I survey the emerging promise that cryptoeconomics presents, followed by an analysis of what appear to be its emerging limitations. Finally, I outline suppositions about how cryptoeconomics might mature by incorporating forms of politics in which economics serves as a means more than an end, where the range of motion available in governance is as wide as possible. I hope that these observations can inform both future practice and empirical research; if cryptoeconomics is running up against its limits, future scholarship and entrepreneurship alike should take care not to be constrained by it.
I land on an argument that is both descriptive and prescriptive, though perhaps anticlimactic for a technology that inspires such utopian aspirations: cryptoeconomic projects need to rediscover older habits of political life. This entails enveloping economics within rules set by institutions not primarily economic in nature, which are capable of articulating, instantiating, and evolving shared understandings of the common good. The argument entails that it is not enough to produce confidence machines without undertaking the forever uncertain work of cultivating trust.
This article joins an expanding literature on cryptoeconomic governance. The literature largely agrees that cryptoeconomics introduces novel governance instruments with consequences that deserve further study. Cryptoeconomics has been notable, for instance, in achieving more rapid growth and adoption than other recent efforts to organize complementary and alternative currencies (Meyer and Hudon 2019); distributed ledgers have meanwhile amassed significant value outside the control of corporations or governments, making the question of how to govern them urgent and yet beyond the reach of prevailing regimes. Although it is far from clear what role cryptoeconomic systems will play in the economy and society of the future, the actually existing experiments contain innovations in governance that attract persistent interest (El Faqir et al. 2020, Wright and Law 2021, e.g., Wharton Cryptogovernance Workshop n.d.).
Some of these innovations include:
To illustrate at least some of these innovations, I will briefly introduce three projects. These were among the many examples that informants described in interviews, selected here to represent the breadth of current cryptoeconomic practice.
The name Kleros comes from the Greek word for randomness, referencing ancient Athens’s use of lotteries to choose government officials. It is a cryptoeconomic court built on the Ethereum protocol. Case 532 posed the question “Will Joe Biden win the 2020 United States presidential election?” The case originated from Omen, an Ethereum prediction market, where that question amassed $1.45 million in trading volume.[3] The arbiter of the answer was to be reality.eth, a cryptoeconomic “oracle”—referencing another, more mystical feature of ancient Greek politics—that crowdsources verification of real world events. The oracle failed to reach a determination, so the case went to its predefined arbitrator, Kleros. There, the matter was settled in favor of President-Elect Biden on December 20, 2020—two weeks before a mob attacked the US Capitol seeking to overturn the election—by a jury whose members had to stake tokens in order to participate. The jurors stood to earn rewards choosing the winning outcome. This process implements the “Schelling point” concept in game theory: the conclusion that participants think other participants will independently choose (Aouidef et al. 2021, Dylag and Smith 2021).
Such a jury does not deliberate, does not seek a common good together; its members unite through self-interest. Before coming to the jury, the factual basis of the case was supposed to come not from official organs or respected news organizations but from anonymous users jointly disciplined by reward-seeking. The prediction market itself was premised on the supposition that people make better forecasts when they stand to gain or lose the equivalent of money in the process. The politics of the presidential election in question, here, had been thoroughly transmuted into a cluster of economies.
The Graph is a protocol that facilitates data queries on decentralized networks. It is a piece of cryptoeconomic infrastructure that many other projects rely on, and its GRT utility tokens represented a market capitalization peak of $2,878,164,921 in February 2021. Graph Improvement Proposal GIP-0002 sought a technical change in the protocol to “separate destination address for Indexer indexing rewards.” A specific implementation of the proposal resided on Radicle, a decentralized code-hosting platform. Discussion occurred on a Discourse-based forum, where it garnered nearly two hundred comments. Following the process outlined earlier in GIP-0001, a poll took place on Snapshot,[4] a platform that allows users to vote with their token holdings; between March 9 and March 16, 2021, 99.72 percent of the GRT tokens that voted did so in favor of the change. That poll was not in itself binding. On March 23, a forum post announced that the Graph Council, a group of network participants that controls changes to the protocol, would delay the implementation due to concerns raised since the poll. Not until March 29 was the proposal actually added to the protocol, to be followed by proposals that could address concerns that arose in the process.
Rather than relying on direct token voting, as some other protocols have done, The Graph uses a board-like mediating layer, the Graph Council, on which the protocol’s major stakeholder groups have representatives. In this case, the proposal had the potential to favor one group of stakeholders over others, and passing a decision through the Council required multiple stakeholder groups to agree. At the same time, the Snapshot vote put pressure on the Council to implement the will of token-holders.
“Honey is money, for everybody,” the website explains.[5] 1Hive is a “community,” backed by no company or other legal entity, that has its own token (Honey), exchange (Honeyswap), financial products (Honeycomb), constitution (Community Covenant), and dispute-resolution system (Celeste). The Honey token had a peak market capitalization of $29,135,127 in March 2021. Decisions occur through “conviction voting,” which weighs power to participants who indicate a consistent preference by staking tokens over time (Emmett 2019). Community members communicate on a Discourse forum, Discord chat, and Telegram chat, each of which requires a separate account. A system called Pollen distributes rewards of Honey based on a user’s participation on the 1Hive Discord, Discourse, and GitHub spaces. A 3,180-word post on the forum, “Everything about 1Hive in one place,” details the steps necessary to get all of one’s accounts and wallets and tokens in order enough to participate (Eth_man 2020), indicating an extensive process.
The purpose of 1Hive appears to be dual. On the one hand, it is “money,” under the aegis of a cartoon bee. A community currency flows through 1Hive’s platforms to encourage pro-social behavior. And yet the Community Covenant puts the goal in less financial terms: “1Hive is a community of activists seeking to build a future that is more free, fair, open, and humane.” The cryptoeconomic juries of Celeste serve to enforce the qualitative values of the Covenant (sacha 2021). According to a slogan that appears repeatedly in 1Hive discussions, “Come for the honey, stay for the bees.” That is, although economics figures prominently as one first encounters and explores 1Hive, participants understand the community’s primary value as interpersonal, social, and non-economic.
During the cryptocurrency bull market of 2017, governance was often treated like a problem to be solved by a uniform and scalable solution. Projects such as Aragon, Colony, and DAOStack set out to become the operating systems for governing diverse kinds of networks, thanks to airtight cryptoeconomics and user-friendly platforms (El Faqir et al. 2020). By the time of the 2020–2021 bull market, cryptoeconomic governance had become more a reality than just an intention. It was also fragmented and scattered, taking place across diverse and cobbled-together sets of tools, many providing governance mechanisms unfamiliar in legacy institutions. Cryptoeconomic governance did not appear to be converging toward a single mechanism but was diverging into webs of diverse and interconnected processes. From the Kleros judiciary to 1Hive’s various social halls, economic incentives are present at every layer, even where participants articulate non-economic goals. Lane Rettig of Spacemesh says, “It is turtles all the way down”—meaning, by turtles, that cryptoeconomic systems sit atop more cryptoeconomics, and so on (personal communication, April 27, 2021).
Enthusiasts envision that DAOs will someday reorganize every level of organizational life, and perhaps they will. Current practice suggests that doing so would mean a radical financialization of everyday interactions. Projects apparently engaged in non-financial activities, like the immersive game Decentraland and the social-media network Hive (not to be confused with 1Hive), differ little from their corporate competitors except by distributing power through along cryptoeconomic lines and providing new means of commodifying the experience. Vote-buying, a practice usually considered anathema in legacy political systems, has risen to an art in crpytoeconomic design (Buterin et al. 2018, Automata Finance 2021), suggesting a culture in which economics is a preferable replacement for politics.
Cryptoeconomics also serves as a kind of “overlapping consensus” (Rawls 1987) that enables people with diverse aims and social visions to work together. Designers describe this in terms of aiming for “credible neutrality” (Buterin 2020) through systems apparently free of bias toward any set of participants. Aiding claims to neutrality is the apparent transparency of a public blockchain, where the visibility of transaction data is integral to its value and function (Caliskan 2020). Built-in neutrality and transparency offer the prospect of previously untenable coordination among parties without another basis for trust.
Yet, as the processes of The Graph suggest, cryptoeconomic mechanisms are only part of the story. De Filippi and Loveluck (2016) pointed out an “invisible politics” at work in the early Bitcoin community; practices opaque to blockchain ledgers remain integral to crypto governance in practice. Personal relationships, cabals, private chat groups, invite-only calls, and other flows of “off-chain” power shape whatever appears “on-chain.” In earlier-stage projects aspiring to “progressive decentralization”—that is, gradually expanding ownership and control from a particular founder or company to a wider community of stakeholders (Walden 2020)—participants perform cryptoeconomics even where it does not yet fully reign, because cryptoeconomics is the engine of the confidence machine. When the machine is not yet fully operational, cryptoeconomic performances can engender trust until confidence presumably replaces them.
One can also find longings for less-economic logics among cryptoeconomic designers. Maria P. Gomez Gelvez, an advisor to Orca Protocol and former Aragon employee, believes that “a DAO is closer to a country than to a corporation” (personal communication, May 20, 2021). The Graph team rejects the goal of simple profit maximization in favor of more capacious stakeholder governance (Ramirez 2020). Gitcoin founder Kevin Owocki wrote in a tweet, “The momentum behind ETH/Defi has a greater purpose than profit,” and describes Gitcoin’s purpose with the economic concept of “public goods,” which often require non-market forces to produce (Owocki 2021). Later in the same Twitter thread, he added [sic], “i only hope we dont let people down + actually create lasting good [heart emoji].” Ethereum founder Vitalik Buterin has lamented that “plutocracy is still bad,” despite its prevalence in cryptoeconomic systems, including the one he founded (Buterin 2018). He has also called for ways of determining community membership beyond simple token-holding (Buterin 2021a). And yet he maintains, “The answer is what we’ve been saying all along: cryptoeconomics” (Buterin 2018).
If the purpose of a governance system is to enable participants to have as much self-determination as possible—a tolerable oversimplification, I hope—whatever inhibits that self-determination becomes a limitation. If a governance system faces serious limitations on its ability to problem-solve, how deserving is it of either trust or confidence?
The purpose of this section is to identify the limitations on governance that reliance on cryptoeconomics currently does or might incur. I review several apparent limitations. These reflect widely recognized attributes of cryptoeconomic systems; they are also sites of active development that may change as practice evolves. But for now, I argue, these limitations suggest that older concerns about the corrosive effects of economics on democratic governance are also relevant to distributed ledgers.
One important root of these limitations is the blindness of cryptoeconomics to the identity and integrity of human users—a persistent, but not necessarily permanent condition. In many pre-digital political and economic governance systems, identifying participants is not an existential problem. Difficulties arise in edge-cases. Fraud, which can be minimized with laws that threaten to punish it. Authorities may not have simple processes in place for when citizens’ names or gender identification changes. Refugees crossing borders may have trouble identifying themselves or have hostile governments suppress their identities outright. But many people find that they can take government-based identity infrastructure for granted. Dominant Internet platforms have also come to incorporate users’ politically defined identities into their systems, either directly (such as by requiring government-issued identification) or indirectly (such as through bank accounts or phone numbers).
Cryptoeconomics typically seeks to avoid reliance on centralized institutions such as governments. For developers of distributed-ledger systems, representing the personhood of participants is a chronic problem, precisely because of how cryptography obscures its users and how economic incentives reward deception. A common anxiety is the danger of “Sybil” attacks, in which a single user can benefit by masquerading as many users (Conte de Leon et al. 2017). Such attacks can be easy and damaging. Some applications may require users to verify their identities by multiple means, such as by posting a code on social media accounts, producing a video of themselves, and submitting biometric data (Siddarth et al. 2020). In cryptoeconomic contexts, personhood cannot be taken for granted, and establishing it incurs costs. Enduring a complex process of identity verification, for instance, may prevent less-motivated users from completing the on-boarding process, thus reducing adoption.
For many blockchain enthusiasts, the lack of reliance on personal identity is a feature not a bug, offering advantages in terms of privacy and permissionless participation. Cryptoeconomics could also produce identification protocols that improve on existing options, such as through “self-sovereign identity” mechanisms based on reputation and mutual attestation of others across a network (Tobin and Reed 2017). This approach could give users unprecedented control over how they represent themselves and could be less vulnerable to the coercion or collapse of governments. But cryptoeconomics has yet to deliver a widely adopted means of identifying unique human users. Therefore the control of economic units, rather than units based on personhood, remains the basic logic of governance. This presents challenges for governance if personhood should still possess intrinsic importance.
The prevailing consensus mechanisms, known as “proof of work” and “proof of stake,” grant governance rights roughly in proportion to a given node’s buy-in on the network—through computing power or token holdings, respectively. Applications and organizations built on such networks tend to follow a similar logic, granting power to whomever holds their tokens. Those with more tokens than others hold more decision-making power than others. Vitalik Buterin (2018) therefore comes by his anxieties about plutocracy honestly; rule according to wealth has so far been the norm in cryptoeconomic designs.
Governance by economics is nothing new. Joint-stock companies conventionally operate on plutocratic governance—more shares equals more votes. This arrangement is economically efficient for aligning shareholder interests, even while it may sideline such externalities as fair wages and environmental impacts. Yet companies operate within the constraints of state policy, which ultimately govern obligations among state-recognized persons, whether corporate or natural. The earliest companies formed to fulfill the charters of mercantilist monarchs; today, companies must at least adhere to the rules of governments that purport to represent the will of society as a whole, not just the company’s participants. Governments impose rules about transparency, conduct, accounting, equity trading, and more. So while plutocracy is prevalent in the joint-stock universe, governments can counteract it through progressive taxation, collective bargaining rights, environmental regulations, antitrust enforcement, and more. If distributed ledgers are based on cryptoeconomics “all the way down,” without an underlying political order, such options are not available. But if “a DAO is closer to a country than to a corporation,” participants will expect countermeasures against rule by wealth.
For cryptoeconomic systems, as in many economic markets, a critical means of accountability and redress against plutocracy is user exit—leaving one network and moving to a more agreeable one; in some cases, users have succeeded in challenging takeover attempts by exiting a protocol and starting again on their own (Caliskan 2021, Ba et al. 2022). The prospect of participants voting with tokens also provides opportunities for effective voice rarely available in online platforms (Frey and Schneider 2021). This kind of voice, however, has persistently favored wealthier participants and institutional investors, frustrating people attracted by the prospect of shared governance. The persistent dominance of early-to-market blockchains like Bitcoin and Ethereum means that cryptoeconomics also lends outsized power to their early adopters. Mechanisms like quadratic voting (Buterin et al. 2018, Wright 2019–2020) and 1Hive’s conviction voting can reduce plutocracy by balancing the influence of large vote-buyers with the degree of preference among smaller token-holders. But this may come at the cost of greater vulnerability to Sybil attacks in the absence of robust means of establishing personhood.
For now, plutocracy may be endemic in cryptoeconomic systems. Ferreira et al. (2019) predict a high likelihood of corporate capture in proof-of-work blockchains such as Bitcoin. Some hope that the influence of venture-capital firms in token markets might be warded off with efficient vote-selling (Automata Finance 2021) or other incentive designs that make plutocracy less attractive (Buterin 2018, Eyal 2019). But as long as governance is reducible to economics, it will be difficult to prevent the feedback loops between wealth and power from spiraling into plutocratic outcomes.
Like economics itself, cryptoeconomics is surely normative as well as descriptive. Ferraro et al. (2005) find across numerous studies that “self-interested behavior is learned behavior, and people learn it by studying economics and business.” Although this picture of human flourishing finds limited validation in empirical psychology and anthropology, homo economicus has spread across organizational life through managers with economics-informed business education. It shapes the institutions people create, as well as people themselves.
The anthropology underlying cryptoeconomic institutional design—“explicit economic incentives for good behavior and economic penalties for ba[d] behavior” (Buterin 2018)—assumes that users have a common desire to maximize their economic rewards; incentives based on those rewards comprise the structure of organizations and nudge the behavior of participants. Remarkably, cryptoeconomic design has produced multi-billion-dollar financial networks that are resistant to fraud, without government coercion to enforce their claims. Yet perhaps the anthropology embedded in these systems—that homo crpytoeconomicus of incentive nudges—helps explain why distributed-ledger adoption has been primarily among finance-related applications, a field already premised on self-interested value-maximizing. Outside of finance, people might expect systems that can see different sides of their natures.
The subjectivity of a cryptoeconomic juror on Kleros seeking to earn a fee is surely different from that of jurors deliberating in a legal courtroom, repeatedly reminded of their civic duty. “Community” takes on a different meaning if it is a fandom of authors freely sharing fan-fiction, in comparison to Honey-holders in 1Hive who stand to profit from the market value of their shared token.
Relying on cryptoeconomic incentives limits governance to a narrow subset of the techniques that other kinds of institutions have used. Cryptoeconomics sees only a certain slice of the people involved. Concepts such as self-sacrifice, duty, and honor are bedrock features of most political and business organizations, but are difficult to simulate or approximate with cryptoeconomic incentive design. Labor unions can produce economic benefits for members, but achieving and maintaining those benefits has required cultivating an “expanded community of fate” that is anything but self-interested (Levi 2020). As Albert O. Hirschman (1970) famously showed, the most economically valuable forms of organizational loyalty often grow out of non-economic forms of relationship. When people complain that others seem to vote against their own economic interests, it should be a reminder that economic interests do not encapsulate the totality of human needs and wants (Haidt 2012). Governance regimes should reflect that multiplicity.
In a survey of diverse governance domains, Gritsenko and Wood (2020) found that, while introducing algorithmic processes can increase efficiency, doing so also results in “decreasing the space for governing actors’ discretion.” Algorithms can also increase the space of their initial designers’ power, compared to the power of future users (Galloway 2006). Incentive-based systems meanwhile have trouble seeing aspects of the world around them not already captured in algorithms.
On May 13, 2021, the billionaire entrepreneur Elon Musk issued a statement that his company Tesla would stop accepting Bitcoin for car purchases due to concerns about the cryptocurrency’s fossil-fuel usage, almost instantly causing a 10 percent dive in Bitcoin’s value (Livni 2021). In the guise of an erratic celebrity with complex business motives, this was a rare case in which Bitcoin faced at least a semblance of accountability for its country-sized energy consumption and environmental impact. Its proof-of-work system is governed by its users—especially the “miners” who carry out energy-intensive computation—and those users may stand to benefit from ignoring their collective carbon footprint. A busier network roughly correlates to higher energy consumption and a higher trading price. Competing cryptocurrencies have promised lower environmental impact, but the incentives associated with Bitcoin’s dominant market position have prevented mass exodus.
The environmental costs are classic externalities—invisible to the feedback loops that the system understands and that communicate to its users as incentives. Other externalities relevant to distributed ledgers include money laundering, dealings in dangerous drugs and weaponry, tax evasion, and the growth of ransomware attacks on public infrastructure that cryptocurrencies have facilitated.
Non-cryptoeconomic systems have some similar properties; shareholders of oil companies also have incentives to pollute, and paper money can support dangerous black markets. But such abuses, at least in principle, are subject to oversight and enforcement by governments tasked with protecting the common good. Political processes enable participants to negotiate compromises among a variety of economic and non-economic interests. If the firm on its own does not see a given externality, the regulatory layer can compel it to do so, such as through disclosure requirements or selective taxation. The externality thus becomes visible to the firm’s incentive structures. For distributed ledgers, similar oversight remains either crude or nonexistent.
Cryptoeconomics can accommodate designs that integrate new variables into their incentive structures; Bitcoin could conceivably incorporate a software update with incentives for reducing energy consumption. Oracle mechanisms like that of reality.eth, which resulted in Kleros case 532, enable cryptoeconomic systems to take input from arbitrary phenomena that would otherwise be outside the view of their algorithms. Non-fungible tokens (NFTs) have made representations of non-quantifiable works of art legible and quantifiable on distributed ledgers. If things must be quantified to be seen, however, do all forms of value lend themselves equally to quantification?
The challenge of funding “public goods” is another example of an externality—and one that threatens the sustainability of cryptoeconomic systems (Buterin et al. 2018). As has been the case for commons-based software in general (Arp et al. 2018), market mechanisms struggle to support critical infrastructure that does not produce direct financial returns. Non-market institutions such as governments and (at vastly smaller scales) charities have been necessary for the provision of public goods before cryptoeconomics; increasingly, distributed ledgers are reinventing them through fee-funded treasuries and donor grant pools. In these and other respects, cryptoeconomic designers are beginning to venture into the realm of the political.
Julia Rosenberg and Maria P. Gomez Gelvez of Orca Protocol have noticed a phenomenon that the cryptoeconomic confidence machines were supposed to do away with: the emergence of “protocol politicians” who gain outsized power through delegated tokens (personal communication, May 20, 2021). In a quest to create a “people-first” system for “governance that works,” Orca instead enables DAOs to delegate decisions more intentionally to various “pods” of qualified users. Joining a pod requires some cryptoeconomic ante, such as staked tokens or evidence of participation. But once over that threshold, pod members deliberate and decide in a less-economic virtual space, where they can be insulated from the short-term incentives that might otherwise steer a vote among token-holders at large. The pods are a way of carefully re-inserting pockets of trust, and of human politics, into technology that was supposed to be trustless—even if it never really was (Alston 2021a). They are one example of how entrepreneurs have sought to balance cryptoeconomics with the mounting recognition that politics is already in their midst and must be accounted for in their designs.
Recent cryptoeconomic practice appears to be reinventing some old wheels of institutional life. The Kleros judiciary, the board-like Graph Council, the constitutionalism of 1Hive, the protocol politicians—they are not the same as their old-world counterparts, but their reappearance also suggests a growing recognition of the need for political institutions in some form. The implementations break from past practice in intriguing ways, often opening the doors wider for participation and transparency. But if mechanisms such as these rely on cryptoeconomics as their sole logic, their feats of liberation will come with limitations on the range of motion for governance.
I argue here that pairing cryptoeconomics with political systems can help overcome the limitations that bedevil cryptoeconomic governance alone. This is not an argument against cryptoeconomics altogether. Nor am I arguing that political mechanisms must occur in every app and protocol. Liberal democratic theory permits diverse forms of association and business within a democratic structure, and similarly politics may be necessary only at key leverage points in an ecosystem to overcome the limitations of cryptoeconomics alone. A napkin sketch of classical, never-quite-achieved liberal democracy (Brown 2015) would depict a market (governed through economic incentives) enclosed in politics (governed through deliberation on the common good). Economics has its place, but the system is not economics all the way down; the rules that guide the market, and that enable it in the first place, are decided democratically, on the basis of citizens’ civil rights rather than their economic power. By designing democracy into the base-layer of the system, it is possible to overcome the kinds of limitations that cryptoeconomics is vulnerable to, such as by counteracting plutocracy with mass participation and making visible the externalities that markets might otherwise fail to see. Doing so, however, may require giving up core aspects of cryptoeconomic thinking, such as the belief that maximal openness, decentralization, and economic incentives are appropriate solutions for all problems.
This section introduces several approaches to inscribing intentional politics into and around distributed ledgers—moving from external interventions through state regulation to interventions more internal to the design of systems.
After raising early concerns about the erosion of the political by the economic, Marcella Atzori (2015) argues that the state should assert itself to ensure democratic control over blockchain networks. This is already happening, to the extent that governments are intervening in the taxation, securities compliance, and mining of these systems. The US Securities and Exchange Commission has indicated a safe harbor from securities regulation for distributed-ledger systems whose control is “sufficiently decentralized” (Hinman 2018)—providing an important incentive for projects to practice at least some of the decentralization that they so often preach. Jurisdictions such as the US state of Wyoming have developed blockchain-friendly incorporation statutes (Wright and Law 2021). China and Russia have attempted to establish cryptocurrencies of their own, while also placing sweeping prohibitions on blockchains they do not control. On smaller scales, local governments have experimented with complementary cryptocurrencies alongside existing money (Diniz et al. 2021).
In most cases, relying solely on governments inhibits at least some of what cryptoeconomics promises, such as the ability to experiment with radically diverse governance, permissionless participation, and censorship resistance (Alston 2021b). Dependence on territorial regimes also lessens the capacity of these technologies to enable equality among users across borders.
State regulation is one tool for disciplining cryptoeconomics with democracy, and it can be a productive one, particularly when states provide a framework that encourages innovation and inhibits abuse (COALA 2021). But leaning on governments too heavily could undermine cryptoeconomic possibilities altogether. The extent of democracy actually present in such governments may be limited or nonexistent. Distributed ledgers can be a design space for democratic practice that governments may be unable to explore on their own, due to gridlock or path dependency. It is probably not sufficient or desireable to merely outsource politics to governments.
Cooperative business is a social movement and regulatory regime that locates democratic ownership and governance in firms among active participants rather than among outside investors (Schneider 2018). Cooperatives blend person-centric governance (one member, one vote) with market-based incentives (patronage dividends in proportion to participation). This model has historically served as a social and legal framework for activities that DAOs and other distributed-ledger projects seek to enable, such as accepting small, early-stage investment from participants and distributing financial rewards. The cooperative principles of autonomy and member control resemble widespread cryptoeconomic aspirations (Crandall 2019, Walden 2019, Davila 2021), while “concern for community” encourages internalizing social externalities (International Co-operative Alliance 2018). Cooperativism provides a framework for democratic governance that can help counteract plutocratic tendencies. For these reasons, a growing number of blockchain projects are incorporating as cooperative legal entities. Kleros operates through a cooperative legal structure in France (Ast and O’Rorke 2018). The US entrepreneur John Paller has taken advantage of flexible cooperative statutes in the state of Colorado to form the legal basis of two tokenized projects: Opolis, an employment platform, and ETHDenver, a conference that attracts international Ethereum developers and investors (Ahonen 2021, Radebaugh and Muchnik 2021).
Cooperative structures could reside primarily at the legal layer, or they could guide the design of distributed ledgers themselves, such as through decision-making based on egalitarian membership rather than token holdings. The largely abandoned cryptocurrency FairCoin implemented a novel consensus mechanism called “proof of cooperation” that sought to ground its cryptoeconomics in cooperative membership among participant organizations that served as network nodes (König et al. 2018). More recently, a series of manifestos have called for “distributed cooperative organizations,” or DisCOs, integrating distributed ledgers and cooperative values, as well as feminist commitments to reward the care work and public goods that markets often fail to recognize (Troncoso and Utratel 2020). Distributed ledgers could also enable cooperatives that self-govern by methods not found among offline cooperatives, from Kleros-like random juries (Fan and Zhang 2020) to “liquid” delegation of representatives in real time (Blum and Zuber 2016). In a call for “moving beyond coin governance,” Buterin (2021b) points to “proof of personhood” and “proof of participation” systems that could tie governance to the logics of human persons and contribution—using cryptoeconomics to reinvent democratic strategies that offline cooperatives have employed for generations.
A cooperative ledger could govern a particular application, as in the case of Opolis or Kleros, or span a larger ecosystem, akin to the role of the Ethereum blockchain in setting ground-rules for the diverse contracts built on top of it. Whereas democracy through state regulation would come from outside the network, cooperative democracy can operate either as the legal basis of a cryptoeconomic system or as its internal logic.
Blockchain-based projects have often claimed to serve social missions, such as economic inclusion, even when little evidence of those missions can be found in their internal cryptoeconomic designs. But there are exceptions. The aborted Ethereum-based project Civil sought to leverage cryptoeconomics to protect journalism against censorship and degraded professional standards (Schneider 2020). Part of the system was the Civil Council, a board of prominent journalists who served as a kind of supreme court for adjudicating the practices of the network’s newsrooms. Token holders could earn rewards by successfully challenging a newsroom’s practices; the success or failure of a challenge ultimately depended on the judgment of the Civil Council, designed to be free of economic incentives clouding its deliberations. In this way, a cryptoeconomic enforcement market served a social mission—a politically defined goal not reducible to economics.
1Hive does something similar with its combination of a values-laden Community Covenant and enforcement through a cryptoeconomic dispute-resolution system; the community proposes this as a replicable model, known as “Gardens,” for other communities to adopt (sacha 2021). Protocols could incorporate “golden share” mechanisms, by which a purpose-focused foundation or member-governed cooperative could hold veto power to ensure a network does not stray from a predefined purpose (Purpose Foundation 2020). Governments have also used golden shares to retain some control over companies managing privatized services (Pezard 1995–1996). Enforceable mission orientation can counteract plutocracy and make externalities more visible to the system.
In their quest for “people-first” governance, the founders of Orca Protocol do not want to depart from economic incentives altogether. But by creating “pods” of users with economic skin in the game, they hope to elevate longer-term thinking over short-term (and potentially short-sighted) feedback loops. Temporal mechanisms can make visible certain externalities that would be less salient under short-term decision-making. The conviction voting system that 1Hive uses, for instance, rewards prolonged commitment. Outside of cryptoeconomics, the US-based Long-Term Stock Exchange is an effort to create an equity market that encourages executives to plan around a more distant horizon than the quarterly cycle that dominates conventional markets. National constitutions generally seek to balance short-term and long-term elected offices, alongside career officials and lifetime appointments. Mechanisms such as term limits, sunset provisions, and reporting requirements can be used to modulate the time-frames around incentives, thereby placing them in the foreground or background, as appropriate.
Long-term incentives are not intrinsically better than short-term ones. But introducing diverse temporal frames can enable diverse inputs, making a system responsive to a wider range of concerns.
Already, a trend toward more complex forms of cryptoeconomic governance reflects a recognition that one-size-fits-all mechanisms are not adequate to the needs of projects or their communities. As Shagun Jhaver (2021) argues, multi-level governance is an important component of successful online communities. And Voshmgir and Zargham (2020) usefully describe blockchains as complex systems, inevitably subject to overlapping influences and emergent properties. Introducing politics at one level of a system, for instance, could enable discrete projects within that system to practice more streamlined “governance minimization” (Ehrsam 2020), deferring potentially costly politics to the level of the system rather than the project. Political logics could be especially valuable at the level of “cross-chain governance” (Chai 2021), which span multiple protocols and may enforce shared standards among them. Politics also inevitably occurs among the interactions of human participants that occur outside the design of the cryptoeconomic system (Shorin et al. 2021)—and that less formal politics deserves further attention.
To the extent that I offer a polemic here, it should not be understood as a call to replace one unified theory with another, but to more fully recognize and cultivate the already existing politics of the field. Cryptoeconomics has never reigned as much as its adherents claim.
When he first introduced Ethereum at a Bitcoin conference in early 2009, Vitalik Buterin ended his talk on the possibilities of distributed-ledger computation with a reference to Skynet—the fictional computer system in the Terminator movies determined to exterminate the human race that created it (Buterin 2014). This bit of hyperbole posed what might still be the fundamental problem of cryptoeconomic governance: How do we design programmable systems that are still accountable to humans and the never-quite-programmable things we care about? Long before blockchains, old-world stock exchanges and corporations produced incentives that stymie efforts to address collective challenges, such as climate change and economic inequality. But the autonomy of cryptoeconomic systems from external regulation could make them even more vulnerable to runaway feedback loops, in which narrow incentives overpower the common good. The designers of these systems have shown an admirable capacity to devise cryptoeconomic mechanisms of many kinds. But for cryptoeconomics to achieve the institutional scope its advocates hope for, it needs to make space for less-economic forms of governance. Through mature designs that integrate with less-economic purposes, cryptoeconomics might transcend its initial limitations.
Politics needs cryptoeconomics, too. Distributed-ledger experiments have produced a uniquely creative barrage of exploration around voting systems, dispute resolution, collective resource management, and other processes that can advance democratic traditions (Allen et al. 2017, Mannan 2018). While political theorists propose introducing mechanisms like sortition in novel ways (Landemore 2020), blockchain communities are already doing so (Aouidef et al. 2021). It may be that a more mature cryptoeconomics can help political systems incorporate an unprecedented diversity of data and feedback loops, across a wider range of concerns. By integrating cryptoeconomics with democracy, both legacies seem poised to benefit. I hope my provocation encourages future explorations into more specific cases of limitations in cryptoeconomic governance and strategies for how less-economic mechanisms might overcome them.
Even short of Skynet, the multi-billion-dollar stakes in distributed-ledger networks today have proven both unnerving and generative. Buterin (2021c) writes, “Crypto is the ultimate training zone: if you can build something that can survive in this environment at scale, it can probably also survive in the bigger world as well.” As this training zone develops, participants should be attentive not only to how their systems succeed and fail in cryptoeconomic terms, but also to what aspects of human flourishing they do not yet take into account. I suspect that doing so will mean building the confidence machine with well-chosen forms of trust.
For purposes of ongoing experimentation, I have obtained quantities of tokens tied with many of the projects mentioned in this paper. I therefore stand to benefit from fluctuations in the value of these tokens, which represents a potential conflict of interest.
Ahonen, E., 2021. Rescuing Crypto Workers from Terrible US Job Conditions: John Paller [online]. Available from: https://cointelegraph.com/magazine/2021/06/22/rescuing-crypto-workers-from-terrible-us-job-conditions-john-paller [Accessed 30 Jun 2021].
Allen, D.W.E., Berg, C., Lane, A.M., and Potts, J., 2017. The economics of crypto-democracy. In: 26th International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence. Presented at the Workshop on Linked Democracy: Artificial Intelligence for Democratic Innovation, Melbourne.
Alston, E., 2019. Constitutions and Blockchains: Competitive Governance of Fundamental Rule Sets. Center for Growth and Opportunity, Utah State University.
Alston, E., 2020. Piercing the Veil of Political Altruism, or, Why Political Rules Are Weird. Free Market Institute, Texas Tech University, No. ID 3702733.
Alston, E., 2021b. Blockchain and the Law: Legality, Law-like Characteristics, and Legal Applications.
Alston, E., 2021a. Norms, Institutions and Digital Veils of Ignorance Do Network Protocols Need Trust Anyway?
Aouidef, Y., Ast, F., and Deffains, B., 2021. Decentralized Justice: A Comparative Analysis of Blockchain Online Dispute Resolution Projects. Frontiers in Blockchain, 4.
Arendt, H., 1998. The Human Condition. 2nd ed. University of Chicago Press.
Arp, L.G., Forbes, M., Cartolano, R.T., Cramer, T., Kimpton, M., Skinner, K., and Whiteside, A.B., 2018. It Takes a Village: Open Source Software Sustainability. LYRASIS.
Ast, F. and O’Rorke, W., 2018. Kleros, the Legal Structure [online]. Available from: https://medium.com/kleros/kleros-the-legal-structure-9cd8fca40b1c [Accessed 12 Nov 2021].
Atzori, M., 2015. Blockchain Technology and Decentralized Governance: Is the State Still Necessary?
Automata Finance, 2021. 1) Automata is a protocol that allows you to sell governance votes… [online]. Available from: https://twitter.com/AutomataFinance/status/1348997992339169280 [Accessed 28 Jun 2021].
Ba, C.T., Zignani, M., and Gaito, S., 2022. The role of groups in a user migration across blockchain-based online social media. In: 2022 IEEE International Conference on Pervasive Computing and Communications Workshops and other Affiliated Events (PerCom Workshops). Presented at the 2022 IEEE International Conference on Pervasive Computing and Communications Workshops and other Affiliated Events (PerCom Workshops), 291–296.
Babbitt, D. and Dietz, J., 2014. Crypto-economic design: A proposed agent-based modeling effort. In: 18th Annual Meeting on Agent-Based Modeling & Simulation. Presented at the SwarmFest 2014, University of Notre Dame.
Barnett, J. and Treleaven, P., 2018. Algorithmic Dispute Resolution of Professional Dispute Resolution Using AI and Blockchain Technologies. The Computer Journal, 61 (3), 399–408.
Beck, R., Müller-Bloch, C., and King, J.L., 2018. Governance in the Blockchain Economy: A Framework and Research Agenda. Journal of the Association for Information Systems, 1020–1034.
Blum, C. and Zuber, C.I., 2016. Liquid Democracy: Potentials, Problems, and Perspectives. Journal of Political Philosophy, 24 (2), 162–182.
Bowles, S., 2016. The Moral Economy: Why Good Incentives Are No Substitute for Good Citizens. New Haven ; London: Yale University Press.
Brekke, J.K. and Alsindi, W.Z., 2021. Cryptoeconomics. Internet Policy Review, 10 (2).
Brown, W., 2015. Undoing the Demos: Neoliberalism’s Stealth Revolution. New York: Zone Books.
Buterin, V., 2014. Vitalik Buterin reveals Ethereum at Bitcoin Miami 2014.
Buterin, V., 2018. Governance, Part 2: Plutocracy Is Still Bad [online]. Available from: https://vitalik.ca/general/2018/03/28/plutocracy.html [Accessed 24 Jun 2021].
Buterin, V., 2020. Credible Neutrality As A Guiding Principle. Nakamoto.
Buterin, V., 2021c. Blockchain voting is overrated among uninformed people but underrated among informed people [online]. Available from: https://vitalik.ca/general/2021/05/25/voting2.html.
Buterin, V., 2021a. ETHDenver 2021 Opening Ceremonies.
Buterin, V., 2021b. Moving Beyond Coin Voting Governance [online]. Available from: https://vitalik.ca/general/2021/08/16/voting3.html [Accessed 19 Aug 2021].
Buterin, V., Hitzig, Z., and Weyl, E.G., 2018. Liberal Radicalism: A Flexible Design For Philanthropic Matching Funds. Social Science Research Network, No. ID 3243656.
Caliskan, K., 2020. Data money: The socio-technical infrastructure of cryptocurrency blockchains. Economy and Society, 49 (4), 540–561.
Caliskan, K., 2021. Data money makers: An ethnographic analysis of a global cryptocurrency community. British Journal of Sociology.
Chai, R., 2021. Cross-chain Governance A New Paradigm [online]. Available from: https://medium.com/iotex/cross-chain-governance-a-new-paradigm-244c81605ca9 [Accessed 18 Aug 2021].
Cila, N., Ferri, G., de Waal, M., Gloerich, I., and Karpinski, T., 2020. The Blockchain and the Commons: Dilemmas in the Design of Local Platforms. In: Proceedings of the 2020 CHI Conference on Human Factors in Computing Systems. New York, NY, USA: Association for Computing Machinery, 1–14.
COALA, 2021. Model Law for Decentralized Autonomous Organizations.
Conte de Leon, D., Stalick, A.Q., Jillepalli, A.A., Haney, M.A., and Sheldon, F.T., 2017. Blockchain: Properties and misconceptions. Asia Pacific Journal of Innovation and Entrepreneurship, 11 (3), 286–300.
Crandall, J., 2019. Blockchains and the ‘Chains of Empire’: Contextualizing Blockchain, Cryptocurrency, and Neoliberalism in Puerto Rico. Design and Culture, 11 (3), 279–300.
Davies, W., 2014. The Limits of Neoliberalism: Authority, Sovereignty and the Logic of Competition. London: SAGE Publications.
Davila, J., 2021. Decentralisation at Work: Cooperatives on the Blockchain [online]. Available from: https://www.dgen.org/blog/decentralisation-at-work-cooperatives-on-blockchain [Accessed 4 Jun 2021].
De Filippi, P. and Loveluck, B., 2016. The invisible politics of Bitcoin: Governance crisis of a decentralised infrastructure. Internet Policy Review, 5 (3).
De Filippi, P., Mannan, M., and Reijers, W., 2020. Blockchain as a confidence machine: The problem of trust & challenges of governance. Technology in Society, 62, 101284.
De Filippi, P. and Wright, A., 2018. Blockchain and the Law: The Rule of Code. Harvard University Press.
Dicker, J., 2021. Cities of Ghosts Await Their DAO Revival [online]. Available from: https://darkstar.mirror.xyz/eYRttcLec0IXODpzLFsHZTRdzuWosBwfyVKnSc93NdA [Accessed 3 Jul 2021].
Diniz, E.H., Cernev, A.K., Rodrigues, D.A., and Daneluzzi, F., 2021. Solidarity cryptocurrencies as digital community platforms. Information Technology for Development, 27 (3), 524–538.
Duffy, K.H., 2017. The Time for Self-Sovereign Identity is Now [online]. Available from: https://medium.com/learning-machine-blog/the-time-for-self-sovereign-identity-is-now-222aab97041b [Accessed 11 Jun 2018].
Dylag, M. and Smith, H., 2021. From cryptocurrencies to cryptocourts: Blockchain and the financialization of dispute resolution platforms. Information, Communication & Society.
Ehrsam, F., 2020. Governance Minimization [online]. Available from: https://www.fehrsam.xyz/blog/governance-minimization [Accessed 18 Aug 2021].
El Faqir, Y., Arroyo, J., and Hassan, S., 2020. An overview of decentralized autonomous organizations on the blockchain. In: Proceedings of the 16th International Symposium on Open Collaboration. Presented at the OpenSym 2020: 16th International Symposium on Open Collaboration, ACM, 1–8.
Emmett, J., 2019. Conviction Voting: A Novel Continuous Decision Making Alternative to Governance [online]. Available from: https://medium.com/commonsstack/conviction-voting-a-novel-continuous-decision-making-alternative-to-governance-62e215ad2b3d [Accessed 24 Jun 2021].
Eth_man, 2020. Everything about 1Hive in one place - newFAQ in development [online]. Available from: https://forum.1hive.org/t/everything-about-1hive-in-one-place-newfaq-in-development/180 [Accessed 24 Jun 2021].
Eyal, A., 2019. The Spacemesh Consensus Protocol [online]. Available from: https://spacemesh.io/protocol/ [Accessed 28 Jun 2021].
Fan, J. and Zhang, A.X., 2020. Digital Juries: A Civics-Oriented Approach to Platform Governance. Presented at the CHI ’20, Honolulu, HI: Association for Computing Machinery, 14.
Faustino, S., 2019. How metaphors matter: An ethnography of blockchain-based re-descriptions of the world. Journal of Cultural Economy, 12 (6), 478–490.
Federici, S., 2004. Caliban and the Witch: Women, the Body and Primitive Accumulation. Brooklyn, NY: Autonomedia.
Ferraro, F., Pfeffer, J., and Sutton, R.I., 2005. Economics Language and Assumptions: How Theories Can Become Self-Fulfilling. The Academy of Management Review, 30 (1), 8–24.
Ferreira, D., Li, J., and Nikolowa, R., 2019. Corporate Capture of Blockchain Governance. European Corporate Governance Institute, No. 593/2019.
Frey, S. and Schneider, N., 2021. Effective Voice: Beyond Exit and Affect in Online Communities. New Media & Society.
Fritsch, F., 2019. The Common Factory: Governance and Incentive Systems of Blockchain-based Social Networks.
Fritsch, F., Emmett, J., Friedman, E., Kranjc, R., Manski, S., Zargham, M., and Bauwens, M., 2021. Challenges and Approaches to Scaling the Global Commons. Frontiers in Blockchain, 4.
Galloway, A.R., 2006. Protocol: How Control Exists After Decentralization. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Giddens, A., 1991. The Consequences of Modernity. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Golumbia, D., 2016. The Politics of Bitcoin: Software as Right-Wing Extremism. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Gritsenko, D. and Wood, M., 2020. Algorithmic governance: A modes of governance approach. Regulation & Governance.
Haidt, J., 2012. Why working-class people vote conservative. The Guardian, 5 Jun.
Hayden, T., 2002. The Zapatista reader. New York: Thunder’s Mouth Press/Nation Books.
Hinman, W., 2018. Digital Asset Transactions: When Howey Met Gary (Plastic).
Hirschman, A.O., 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
International Co-operative Alliance, 2018. Co-operative Identity, Values & Principles [online]. Available from: https://ica.coop/en/whats-co-op/co-operative-identity-values-principles [Accessed 27 May 2018].
Jhaver, S., 2021. Designing for Multiple Centers of Power: Multi-level Governance in Online Social Platforms.
Karjalainen, R., 2020. Governance in decentralized networks.
König, T., Duran, E., Fessler, N., and Alton, R., 2018. The Proof-of-Cooperation Blockchain FairCoin.
Landemore, H., 2020. Open Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Laul, M., 2021. Blockchain Networks Are Bureaucracies Par Excellence [online]. Available from: https://mariolaul.medium.com/blockchains-are-bureaucracies-par-excellence-db39cfda7ea9 [Accessed 15 Jun 2021].
Leach, D.K., 2013. Prefigurative Politics. In: The Wiley-Blackwell Encyclopedia of Social and Political Movements. American Cancer Society.
Levi, M., 2020. An Expanded Community Of Fate. Noema.
Livni, E., 2021. Tesla’s U-turn on Bitcoin raises questions of the cryptocurrency’s stability. The New York Times, 13 May.
Luhmann, N., 2000. Familiarity, Confidence, Trust: Problems and Perspectives. In: D. Gambetta, ed. Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Department of Sociology, University of Oxford.
Mannan, M., 2018. Fostering Worker Cooperatives with Blockchain Technology: Lessons from the Colony Project. Erasmus Law Review, (3), 190–203.
Mannan, M. and Schneider, N., 2021. Exit to Community: Strategies for Multi-Stakeholder Ownership in the Platform Economy. Georgetown Law Technology Review, 5 (1).
Manski, S. and Manski, B., 2018. No Gods, No Masters, No Coders? The Future of Sovereignty in a Blockchain World. Law and Critique, 29 (2), 151–162.
Maurer, B., Nelms, T.C., and Swartz, L., 2013. ‘When Perhaps the Real Problem Is Money Itself!’: The Practical Materiality of Bitcoin. Social Semiotics, 23 (2), 261–277.
Mauss, M., 2006. The Gift: The Form and Reason for Exchange in Archaic Societies. Routledge.
Meyer, C. and Hudon, M., 2019. Money and the Commons: An Investigation of Complementary Currencies and Their Ethical Implications. Journal of Business Ethics, 160 (1), 277–292.
Nakamoto, S., 2009. Bitcoin v0.1 Released [online]. Available from: https://www.mail-archive.com/cryptography@metzdowd.com/msg10142.html [Accessed 2 Jul 2018].
Owocki, K., 2021. The momentum behind ETH/Defi has a greater purpose than profit... [online]. Available from: https://twitter.com/owocki/status/1392474034139406337 [Accessed 24 Jun 2021].
Pezard, A., 1995–1996. The Golden Share of Privatized Companies. Brooklyn Journal of International Law, 21, 85.
Polanyi, K., 2014. The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press.
Purpose Foundation, 2020. Steward-Ownership: A Short Guidebook to Legal Frameworks.
Radebaugh, J. and Muchnik, Y., 2021. Solving the Riddle of the DAO with Colorado’s Cooperative Laws. The Defiant.
Ramirez, B., 2020. Introducing The Graph Council [online]. Available from: https://thegraph.com/blog/introducing-the-graph-council [Accessed 20 Aug 2021].
Rawls, J., 1987. The Idea of an Overlapping Consensus. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 7, 1.
Reijers, W., O’Brolcháin, F., and Haynes, P., 2016. Governance in Blockchain Technologies & Social Contract Theories. Ledger, 1, 134–151.
Reijers, W., Wuisman, I., Mannan, M., De Filippi, P., Wray, C., Rae-Looi, V., Cubillos Vélez, A., and Orgad, L., 2018. Now the Code Runs Itself: On-Chain and Off-Chain Governance of Blockchain Technologies. Topoi.
Rozas, D., Tenorio-Fornés, A., Díaz-Molina, S., and Hassan, S., 2018. When Ostrom Meets Blockchain: Exploring the Potentials of Blockchain for Commons Governance.
Rozas, D., Tenorio-Fornés, A., and Hassan, S., 2021. Analysis of the Potentials of Blockchain for the Governance of Global Digital Commons. Frontiers in Blockchain, 4, 577680.
sacha, 2021. Introducing Gardens: A framework for effective on-chain governance [online]. Available from: https://gardens.substack.com/p/introducing-gardens [Accessed 10 Aug 2021].
Satz, D., 2010. Why Some Things Should Not Be for Sale: The Moral Limits of Markets. OUP USA.
Schneider, N., 2018. Everything for Everyone: The Radical Tradition That Is Shaping the Next Economy. New York: Nation Books.
Schneider, N., 2020. Broad-Based Stakeholder Ownership in Journalism: Co-ops, ESOPs, Blockchains. Media Industries, 7 (2).
Shorin, T., Lotti, L., Lewis, A.Z., Pope, J., and Gomez, M., 2021. Uniswap Research Report: Discord, Governance, Community. Other Internet.
Siddarth, D., Ivliev, S., Siri, S., and Berman, P., 2020. Who Watches the Watchmen? A Review of Subjective Approaches for Sybil-Resistance in Proof of Personhood Protocols. Frontiers in Blockchain, 3, 46.
Stark, J., 2017. Making Sense of Cryptoeconomics. CoinDesk.
Swartz, L., 2017. Blockchain Dreams: Imagining Techno-Economic Alternatives After Bitcoin. In: M. Castells, ed. Another Economy Is Possible: Culture and Economy in a Time of Crisis. Cambridge, UK: Polity, 82–105.
Tobin, A. and Reed, D., 2017. The Inevitable Rise of Self-Sovereign Identity. The Sovrin Foundation.
Troncoso, S. and Utratel, A.M., 2020. Groove is in the Heart: The DiSCO Elements. DisCO.coop.
Voshmgir, S. and Zargham, M., 2020. Foundations of Cryptoeconomic Systems. Vienna, Austria: Vienna University of Economics and Business, No. 1/2020.
Walden, J., 2019. Past, Present, Future: From Co-ops to Cryptonetworks [online]. Available from: https://variant.fund/past-present-future-from-co-ops-to-cryptonetworks/ [Accessed 4 Mar 2019].
Walden, J., 2020. Progressive Decentralization: A Playbook for Building Crypto Applications [online]. Available from: https://a16z.com/2020/01/09/progressive-decentralization-crypto-product-management/ [Accessed 23 Jun 2021].
Wharton Cryptogovernance Workshop, n.d. Governance Assessments.
Wright, A. and Law, C.P. of L. at B.N.C.S. of, 2021. The Rise of Decentralized Autonomous Organizations: Opportunities and Challenges. Stanford Journal of Blockchain Law & Policy.
Wright, D.Jr., 2019–2020. Quadratic Voting and Blockchain Governance. UMKC Law Review, 88 (2), 475–496.